Thoughts on the Murder of Charlie Kirk
Charlie Kirk was murdered last week at a university campus, and the public reaction by many self-identified socialists or communists has shown me just how much socialists and communists share in common with the fascists they claim to despise. One of the many things that fascists, socialists or communists have in common is their hatred for dissenting opinions and their willingness to resort to violence to satisfy their lust for control over people’s lives. Ludwig von Mises observed that “Lenin and Hitler knew very well why they abolished freedom of thought, speech, and the press…Their systems could not survive without concentration camps, censors, and hangmen.” (Mises, 1944, p. 92). Similarly, Charlie Kirk’s murderer could not defeat his opponent with words, and so he resorted to the tactics of despots. Should those who cheer on the murder of political commentators achieve any significant political power, they will not hesitate to use state-sanctioned violence to eliminate dissenters while calling it “justice” and “liberation.”
The communists in China also monopolized the media and outlawed dissenting political speech because their ideology was incapable of surviving long in the marketplace of ideas. The “One Strike and Three Antis” campaign in 1970 during Mao Zedong’s Cultural Revolution resulted in the imprisonment and execution of tens of thousands of Chinese citizens who were guilty of “speech crimes and thought crimes” (Yang, 2016, p. 327). Yang Jisheng describes how the Chinese communists were so fearful of the ideas of those about to be executed that “the authorities went to outrageous lengths to prevent victims from expressing last words by wrapping their necks with ropes, stuffing objects in their mouths, or slitting their larynxes” (Yang, p. 332). In my opinion, there is something symbolic about Charlie Kirk being shot in the neck while in the process of committing what the more anti-social members of the political Left believe to be a speech crime.
Charlie Kirk’s murderer and the people who publicly justify it have done irreparable damage to their cause. So far, the supporters of Charlie Kirk have not resorted to the BLM/Antifa methods of burning down small businesses and beating innocent bystanders while radical academics cheer on the violence from the social media sidelines. Hopefully those who value individual liberty will continue to win hearts and minds through peaceful means, because rational minds will recognize that “Repression by brute force is always a confession of the inability to make use of the better weapons of the intellect—better because they alone give promise of final success” (Mises, 1927, p. 29)
References
Ludwig von Mises (1927). Liberalism: The Classical Tradition. Liberty Fund.
Ludwig von Mises (1944). Bureaucracy. Liberty Fund.
Yang Jisheng (2016). The World Turned Upside Down: A History of the Chinese Cultural Revolution. Picador.
Lenin’s Theory of Imperialism
The Instagram account “leftist.professor.peter” summarizes Vladimir Lenin’s argument that capitalism necessarily leads to imperialism. The account author states: “Lenin argued that imperialism isn’t just about conquest; it’s a natural outcome of capitalism... When capitalism reaches its limits at home, competition creates monopolies, big corporations dominate entire industries... When domestic markets become saturated and resources are fully exploited, they pressure governments to secure new markets and resources abroad… He argued that as long as capitalism exists, powerful nations will seek to dominate weaker ones to maintain economic growth” (https://www.instagram.com/p/DGPQm6Lim63/)
If it were true that big corporations invest in poorer foreign nations to exploit their labor and resources, we would expect to see most foreign investments going to poor countries rather than to rich ones. Thomas Sowell writes that during the time when Lenin published his book on Imperialism, the majority of foreign investment was in other rich nations, not poor nations. When Lenin was claiming the Western world was exploiting underdeveloped nations: “The United States was the largest single recipient of British, German, and Dutch capital” and “the United States invested more in Canada than in all of Africa and Asia put together” (Sowell, 2016, p. 246-247). This was true for most of the 20th century until many Asian nations began to rise in power later that century. Rich nations invest more in other rich nations because they are more productive. Peter Bauer points out that the poorest nations of the world today are those that have the least amount of commercial contact with developed nations. He facetiously remarks that if foreign investment in poorer nations is exploitation, then “the poverty of these countries shows that they have experienced too little rather than too much exploitation” (Bauer, 1976, p. 169).
References
Sowell, T. (2016). Wealth, Poverty and Politics. Basic Books.
Bauer, P. T. (1976). Dissent on Development: Revised Edition. Harvard University Press.
An Unintended Consequence of Affirmative Action
Thomas Sowell in his book Affirmative Action Around the World: An Empirical Study argues that one of the unintended consequences of affirmative action policies designed to benefit minority groups is that they incentivize more people to identify as the preferred minorities. This can end up diluting the benefits which were designated for the intended marginalized populations. Around the world, some people with varying levels of mixed ancestry change their racial identity when the government offers privileges to a specific group. For example, Sowell says that the size of the Native American population dramatically increased after the establishment of various affirmative action policies in the United States. A cohort of 50,000 Native Americans between the ages of 15 and 19 in 1960 increased by roughly 60% to become 80,000 strong in 1980, which Sowell calls “a biological impossibility made possible on paper by redesignations of the same individuals” (p. 8). Some people claiming racial minority status “have included blond-haired and blue-eyed individuals with official papers showing some distant ancestor of another race.” (p. 8). There were similar increases in the ethnically preferred groups in the 1980s among Australia’s aboriginal population and among China’s ethnic minorities in the 1990s. Some Chinese citizens would go back hundreds of years in their ancestry to qualify for government privileges reserved for ethnic minorities.
Reference
Thomas Sowell (2005). Affirmative Action Around the World: An Empirical Study. Yale University Press.
Does “Racial Capitalism” Explain Poverty in the Global South?
Ibram X. Kendi argues that Western exploitation--or what he calls “racial capitalism”-- explains why so many countries in the global south are poor in spite of having rich natural resources. Kendi writes that centuries of Western exploitation “…makes countries like the Democratic Republic of the Congo one of the richest countries in the world belowground and one of the poorest countries in the world aboveground” (Kendi, 2019, p. 163). The problem with Kendi’s explanation is that it fails to explain the vast differences in wealth between Europeans and the region we know today as the Democratic Republic of the Congo before the Europeans ever made any significant contact. Daron Acemoglu and James Robinson write that in the 1400s and 1500s, the Kongo was incredibly poor when the Portuguese and the Dutch first arrived, stating that “Technology was rudimentary by European standards, with the Kongolese having neither writing, the wheel, nor the plow” (Acemoglu & Robinson, 2012, p. 87).
If the Kongo and other African regions were rich in resources before the arrival of Europeans, Peter Bauer asks “Why have the Africans not developed their mineral resources? Why did they have to wait for Europeans to explore, develop, process, and market them?” (Bauer, 2000, p. 76). Bauer observes that when we look at material progress over time, we see that it is not unusual for nations with few resources to become wealthy and nations with abundant resources to remain in poverty. Indigenous peoples in North America had vast resources but little material wealth, and yet nations like Japan, Germany, or Britain had few natural resources but eventually developed much wealth. Natural resources are useless if you do not have the means to use them. Thomas Sowell notes that “The natural resources we use today were even more abundant in the era of the cave man, but the people of that prehistoric era were culturally not yet able to use most of those resources” (Sowell, 2016, p. 89). There are certainly many factors that contribute to the relative wealth and poverty of nations, but Bauer argues that some important factors for material progress include “…personal qualities, social institutions and mores, and political arrangements which make for endeavor and achievement…” (Bauer, 2000, p. 76).
References
Acemoglu, D., & Robinson, J. A. (2012). Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity, and Poverty. Currency.
Bauer, P. (2000). From Subsistence to Exchange and Other Essays. Princeton University Press.
Kendi, I. X. (2019). How to be an Antiracist. One World.
Sowell, T. (2016). Wealth, Poverty, and Politics: Revised and Enlarged Edition. Basic Books.
Reducing Carbon Emissions to Save Underdeveloped Nations
Activists and academics who want to fight climate change sometimes argue we must decrease carbon emissions in order to help underdeveloped nations. Industrialized nations produce disproportionate amounts of carbon and also reap most of its benefits, while underdeveloped nations feel the most negative impact from extreme weather events. If we actually ask people around the world to rank their top policy priorities, we find that the people of the world have a different opinion on how best to help poor nations. Bjorn Lomborg, in his book False Alarm, cites data collected by a global United Nations survey asking 9.7 million of people to rank order their top policy priorities. The top five priorities were Education, Health, Jobs, No corruption, and Nutrition. “Action on climate change” was ranked 16th overall, right behind “phone and internet”. It turns out that climate change is a much bigger deal for richer nations than for people in the poorest nations. Lomborg states “People in rich countries, having much better education, health, and nutrition, tend to be more afraid of climate change, but even for Europeans climate rises only to the tenth-highest concern. For the world’s poorest, climate is robustly last.” Program evaluators who specialize in participatory research methods should be aware of the potential disconnect between what the academics want and what the people they claim to fight for want.
Reference
Bjorn Lomborg (2021). False Alarm: How Climate Change Panic Costs Us Trillions, Hurts the Poor, and Fails to Fix the Planet. Basic Books.
Why do workers earn more in one country than another?
Why is a construction worker in a developed nation paid higher real wages than a construction worker in an underdeveloped nation? Why don’t the governments of poorer nations simply declare a $20 minimum wage to lift all their workers out of poverty? Henry Hazlitt argues that the primary reason why some workers are paid more than others, even though they work in the same industry, is because those who are paid more tend to produce more. One man or woman driving a giant truck or bulldozer can move more raw materials than a hundred people using pickaxes and carrying raw materials on their backs. If we want workers in underdeveloped nations to have a higher quality life, their labor needs to be made more productive through greater capital investment, technological innovation, or better education and training. Hazlitt states that “We cannot in the long run pay labor as a whole more than it produces. The best way to raise wages, therefore, is to raise marginal labor productivity…Real wages come out of production, not out of government decrees” (p. 139).
Reference
Henry Hazlitt (1988). Economics in One Lesson: The Shortest and Surest Way to Understand Basic Economics. Crown Currency.
Zohran Mamdani and State-Run Supermarkets
Zohran Mamdani, the Democratic Mayoral candidate of NYC, wants to establish state-run grocery stores that are designed to save customers’ money by eliminating the profit motive (https://foodtank.com/news/2025/06/city-owned-grocery-stores-a-bold-fix-for-food-insecurity/). Socialists see eliminating the profit motive as a virtue of their various policies and programs, but it is precisely those profits and losses that are necessary for increasing the affordability of goods and services. Walter E. Williams (2008) argues that rather than being exploitative, “profits are incentives for firms to satisfy customers, find least-cost production methods and move resources from low-valued to high-valued uses” (p. 90). Since Zohran Mamdani’s state-run grocery stores will not react to the signals given by profits and losses, they have no incentive to reduce costs or offer higher quality services than their competitors. Ludwig von Mises (1944) points out that if state-run enterprises are not making profits, then they are probably losing money, which means taxpayers will have to make up the difference. Mises writes: “When the government tries to eliminate or to mitigate this dependence [on profits] by covering the losses of its plants and shops… The means for covering the losses must be raised by the imposition of taxes” (p. 70). State-run grocery stores will not save money for New Yorkers overall; they will pay low prices at the cash register—assuming the artificially low prices do not lead to shortages or rationing—but then pay more in taxes to subsidize an inferior product.
References
Ludwig von Mises (1944). Omnipotent Government: The Rise of the Total State and Total War. Liberty Fund.
Walter E. Williams (2008). Liberty vs. The Tyranny of Socialism: Controversial Essays. Hoover Press.
How to Increase Real Wages
Why is a construction worker in a developed nation paid higher real wages than a construction worker in an underdeveloped nation? Why don’t the governments of poorer nations simply declare a $20 minimum wage to lift all their workers out of poverty? Henry Hazlitt argues that the primary reason why some workers are paid more than others, even though they work in the same industry, is because those who are paid more tend to produce more. One man or woman driving a giant truck or bulldozer can move more earth than a hundred people using pickaxes and carrying earth on their backs. If we want workers in underdeveloped nations to have a higher quality life, their labor needs to be made more productive through greater capital investment, technological innovation, or better education and training. Hazlitt states that “We cannot in the long run pay labor as a whole more than it produces. The best way to raise wages, therefore, is to raise marginal labor productivity…Real wages come out of production, not out of government decrees” (p. 139).
Reference
Henry Hazlitt (1988). Economics in One Lesson: The Shortest and Surest Way to Understand Basic Economics. Crown Currency.
Walter E. Williams and Ibram X. Kendi on Welfare Hypocrisy
Conservatives have long criticized welfare programs for being counterproductive. By providing unconditional handouts to the poor, the government encourages people to remain poor by removing their incentive to develop their human capital. Professor Ibram X. Kendi notes that those who take this position are hypocritical for remaining silent when it comes to government handouts for the middle and upper classes. Conservative politicians will blame social problems in the Black American community on government handouts, but at the same time who will say nothing “about rich White people who depended on the welfare of inheritances, tax cuts, government contracts, hookups, and bailouts…the New Deal, the GI Bill, subsidized suburbs, and exclusive White networks” (p. 154).
Libertarian-minded individuals have consistently agreed with Kendi’s critique. If government handouts are detrimental to the poor, then there is no reason why handouts to corporations would be any less deleterious. The economist Walter E. Williams, who was no ally of the political Left or anti-capitalist ideologies, likewise criticized Republicans who support corporate subsidies but oppose federal welfare schemes or student loan forgiveness on the grounds that such policies are too expensive or are immoral because they force one person to pay for the livelihood of another who did not earn it. If Republicans extended their critiques of the welfare state to include the tens of billions of dollars the federal government gives in corporate subsidies, then the nation might actually reduce federal spending. When Republicans were trying to reform welfare in the 1990s, Williams stated: “How can you possibly talk about slamming the handout door on a poor, lazy, good-for-nothing welfare recipient while at the same time sponsoring handouts for members of America’s Fortune 500?...Republicans would be on far greater moral...footing if their version of welfare reform included government corporate handouts” (p. 56-57)
References
Ibram X. Kendi (2019). How to be an Antiracist. One World.
Walter E. Williams (1999). More Liberty Means Less Government: Our Founders Knew This Well. Hoover Institution Press.
Zohran Mamdani Seizing the Means of Production
Videos have surfaced of New York City mayoral candidate Zohran Mamdani claiming that the end goal for socialists like him is to have the government seize and control the means of production. It is easy to believe that our basic needs could more easily be met if we lived in a socialist society where the government controlled all the factories and natural resources, and there would be no more greedy businesspeople exploiting workers and consumers. The government could then create a scientific plan to equitably distribute resources to meet everyone’s needs. This fantasy fails both in theory and in practice. The economist Ludwig von Mises suggests that such a socialist system is bound to fail because without prices, profits, and losses, there is no rational means of allocating scarce resources to meet the most urgent needs. There are millions of ways that workers, factories, and natural resources can be utilized to make consumer goods. In a market economy, all these factors of production are privately-owned, and they are bought and sold at prices that fluctuate according to supply and demand. Entrepreneurs, hoping to earn a profit by fulfilling the needs of consumers, use these prices to calculate the most efficient production methods and shutter enterprises that do not serve consumers at the cheapest cost.
Mises writes that if the government owns all these factors of production and they are simply distributed according to a government plan, then “there would be neither discernible profits nor discernible losses. Where there is no calculation, there is no means of getting an answer to the question whether the projects planned or carried out were those best fitted to satisfy the most urgent needs” (p. 25). The result is economic chaos.
This is not just a theoretical argument. Socialist economists Nikolai Shmelev and Vladimir Popov witnessed the economic calculation problem with their own eyes in the Soviet Union, where the government-planned economy created constant shortages, surpluses, production inefficiencies, and a much poorer quality of life compared to other developed nations. Shmelev and Popov write that for the Soviet Union, shortages and surpluses were “an everyday reality, a governing law. The absolute majority of goods is either in short supply or in surplus… the needed product is almost never present in the needed region in the needed amount” (p. 89). The government planners were unable to predict all the complexity of allocating resources and setting prices, and the people paid dearly for it.
Program evaluators who call for abolishing free markets and replacing them with a system of governance in which the state controls the means of production should be wary of how their ideology put into practice would exacerbate the suffering they desire to alleviate.
References
Ludwig von Mises (1944). Bureaucracy. Liberty Fund, Inc.
Nikolai Shmelev & Vladimir Popov (1989). The Turning Point: Revitalizing the Soviet Economy. Doubleday.
What does it mean to put “People Before Profits”?
A colleague of mine posted on social media that we need more government intervention to put “people before profits.” I think people make such proclamations because they do not understand that striving for profits or minimizing losses actually does benefit the average person. The economist Walter E. Williams argues that profits and losses in general benefit society by forcing businesses to efficiently meet the needs of consumers. Businesses that produce what consumers desire make profits, while those that do not are shut down. Williams also notes that profits incentivize businesses to streamline their production to more efficiently use resources: “If producers waste input, their production costs will be higher and they’ll charge prices higher than what consumers are willing to pay. Therefore, the company will make losses...and go out of business” (p. 5). It is the non-profit and government sectors that are most likely to waste resources and fail to serve their customers. Just ask the university students complaining about skyrocketing student loan debt and their inability to find work after graduation.
Reference
Walter E. Williams (1999). More Liberty Means Less Government: Our Founders Knew This Well. Hoover Institution Press Publication.
Program Evaluation and the Affordable Housing Crisis
Some time ago I saw a San Francisco politician on social media complaining that there is not enough affordable housing for his constituents. His proposed solution was for the government to subsidize the construction of affordable housing units. The assumption underlying this legislation is that high housing costs are a failure of the free market, and politicians must intervene on behalf of the common good. Many economists argue, however, that government interventions to create more affordable housing are trying to correct a problem that was created by government intervention in the first place. Housing costs rise when there are a lot of people bidding for a limited amount of housing. If the supply of housing increases to meet the demand, housing costs will go down. Various government interventions may be responsible for slowing the construction of new housing. The economist Thomas Sowell notes that prior to the 1970s, housing in the San Francisco area and California in general was rather affordable. Sowell states that “the decade of the 1970s marked the beginning of severe government restrictions on the building of houses and apartments. That same decade marked the meteoric rise of housing prices” (p. 28). Government interventions such as “open space laws...zoning laws, environmental laws, historic preservation laws, and others” were implemented with good intentions, but they had the effect of restricting the supply of housing and increasing rents (p. 29).
Program designers and evaluators are tempted to blame social problems on the unregulated market and assume that the solution is to be found in government spending. It is my opinion that program evaluators who are interested in understanding the root causes of a social problem should first consider whether government is the source of the problem, not the solution.
Reference
Thomas Sowell (2011). Economic Facts and Fallacies (2nd edition). Basic Books.
Banning Automation to Save Jobs
I saw an interesting video demonstrating how a company builds concrete homes using a giant 3D printer. This process sounds like a great way to reduce the cost of housing by building houses more quickly and cheaply. One of the commenters on the video, however, lamented that this technology would lead to unemployment in the construction industry, and this in turn would harm the economy. The Hungarian author Marcel Kadosa argues that such a worldview is based on the fallacy of “…treating labor itself as the goal rather than its outcome…” (p. 128). Tools were created to meet our needs using the least amount of labor possible. Our material quality of life is better today than it was 200 years ago in no small part because of the continuous development of labor-saving technology. We could easily create jobs by banning the use of bulldozers and forcing construct workers to dig with their bare hands, but that would make society poorer by diverting resources away from more productive tasks. Kadosa observes that “Industry is valuable not because it provides jobs, but because it supplies us with the things we need. That those engaged in this socially beneficial work make a living from it is merely a consequence of their activity” (p. 122).
Reference
Marcel Kadosa (1925). The Tariff Superstition: Why Protectionism Always Fails—and Who Really Pays the Price. Praxeum.
Do Foreign Investments Impoverish a Nation?
Some people in the United States are concerned that foreigners have invested too much money into the US. Because we import more goods than we export, foreigners get excess dollars and then use those dollars to buy our wealth from under us. This makes us in debt to foreigners, and a nation as powerful as the United States should never be in debt to foreign nations. The economist Thomas Sowell disagrees with this reasoning and argues that foreign investment is a good thing both for the United States and foreign investors. He writes that “Despite fears in some countries that foreign investors would carry off much of their national wealth…there is probably no country in history from which foreigners have carried away more vast amounts of wealth than the United States” (p. 509). If it were true that foreign investment robs Americans of their wealth, then “Americans ought to be some of the poorest people in the world” (p. 509). And yet Americans are some of the richest people in the world. The United States has received massive foreign investments for generations, which means we have been indebted for foreigners for generations. The reason why America continues to grow in spite of being in debt to foreign investors is because both sides benefit when these economic transactions takes place. If both sides did not benefit then they would not agree to it. Foreign investors are confident they will get a return on their investment, and American entrepreneurs are confident they can pay the investors back while still earning profits for themselves. This economic activity creates productive jobs and produces better goods and services to improve the average citizen’s material quality of life.
Reference
Thomas Sowell (2014). Basic Economics: A Common Sense Guide to the Economy (5th edition). Basic Books.
Can you have too much income equality?
Income inequality has become one of the primary concerns of program evaluators who wish to participate in creating a more equitable society, but is it possible to have too much income equality? The Soviet Union provides an interesting case study. Socialist economists Nikolai Shmelev and Vladimir Popov observed that the Soviet Union in the 1980s had much more income equality than did the United States. This is because prices and wages were determined by government officials rather than the profit and loss system of the market. Even though the Soviet Union had more equality than the United States, they were far worse off than the average American in material terms. By removing the possibility of being rewarded for harder work or greater efficiency, the quality and quantity of goods and services were abysmal. Shmelev and Popov state that Soviet price controls and leveling wages “…created a welfare mentality” where workers knew they could never get rich but also that they would always have employment (p. 177). This government mandated equality “suppresses any incentive to work, causes shake-ups, lack of discipline, and a parasitic certainty of a guaranteed income that does not depend on one’s actual contribution to the job…” (p. 187). I personally would rather be unequal and prosperous than be poor and equal.
Reference
Nikolai Shmelev & Vladimir Popov (1989). The Turning Point: Revitalizing the Soviet Economy. Doubleday.
Tax Rates vs. Tax Revenues
Some people take it for granted that if a state or federal government is lacking in tax revenues, then it can simply raise taxes on the rich to gather additional revenue. This assumes that those who have their taxes raised will simply go about doing what they were doing before without changing their behavior. Thomas Sowell calls this the “chess piece fallacy.” If taxes are too punitive, those who pay them may be incentivized to move elsewhere, leaving the government with less than what it started with. In one example, Sowell observes that the state of Maryland tried to raise tax revenues “by increasing the tax rate on people whose incomes were a million dollars a year or more. But, by the time the new tax rate took effect in 2008, the number of such people living in Maryland had declined from nearly 8,000 to fewer than 6,000. The tax revenues... actually fell instead by more than $200 million” (p. 51). Just because a tax-rate increases does not necessarily mean there will be an increase in tax revenues. Understanding these sorts of trade-offs may be relevant to the field of program evaluation. What good are government social programs if they lead to expanding budgets that chase away their tax base? If the goal of program evaluation is to improve social programs to serve the “common good,” then evaluators must acknowledge that even if an evaluation shows that social program participants are better off than a comparison group, that in no way confirms that they would be better off if no program had existed in the first place.
References
Thomas Sowell (2023). Social Justice Fallacies. Basic Books.
China’s Population Control
Environmental extremists have for years called on governments enact policies to reduce the growth of the human population to prevent the complete exhaustion of scarce resources and a declining quality of life for the average person. Contrary to what the environmentalists have predicted, resources are becoming more abundant and quality of life for the average person across the globe has been improving. Thankfully their recommendations for population control were not taken seriously in the United States or Europe. Unfortunately, China took the warnings of these environmentalists seriously and destroyed many lives in the process. China’s one-child policy—which lasted from 1979 to 2015—was designed to reduce the Chinese population by punishing women who gave birth to more than one child. They implemented this policy under the false belief that an increasing population would drain China’s scarce resources. Chelsea Follett from the Cato Institute describes the human rights abuses of the Chinese government in some detail. The one-child policy was enforced through the termination of pregnancies, massive fines, mandated pregnancy tests, forced international adoption, and robbing and destroying private property. Local government officials were penalized for not maintaining the one-child quota and were rewarded bonuses for sterilizing women. Follett describes the scale of the sterilization campaigns, stating that between 1979 and 2015, the Chinese government had “over 300 million Chinese women fitted with intrauterine devices modified to be irremovable without survey, over 100 million sterilizations, and over 300 million abortions. Many of these procedures were coerced” (p. 1). In 2017, the UN estimated that “18.3 percent of Chinese women aged 15-49 had been permanently sterilized” (p. 9).
Reference
Chelsea Follett (2020). Neo-Malthusianism and Coercive Population Control in China and India. Cato Institute, Policy Analysis, No. 897. Retrieved from: https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3660007
Shouldn’t Environmentalists Be Happy About High Oil Prices?
Why do politicians who want to fight climate change by reducing our consumption of oil get angry when the price of oil increases? They condemn the oil companies for price-gouging and threaten to tax away their profits unless they reduce their prices. If your goal, however, is to get people to use less oil, the best thing greedy oil corporations can do is to price-gouge the citizens. As Thomas Sowell states, “There is perhaps no more basic or more obvious principle of economics than the fact that people tend to buy more at a lower price and less at a higher price” (p. 28). If oil prices skyrocket, then people consume less oil and seek cheaper forms of alternative energy. Yet politicians take the logically inconsistent position of wanting people to use less oil but also claim to want to lower its price. I wonder if this inconsistency is intentional; politicians do everything in their power to make fossil fuels more expensive, and then earn votes from the working-class by blaming big business.
Reference
Thomas Sowell (2014). Basic Economics: A Common Sense Guide to the Economy (5th edition). Basic Books.
The Problem with Anti-Price Gouging Laws
Many people on both ends of the political spectrum would agree that price controls on goods and services during normal times are a bad idea. If prices are not allowed to fluctuate according to supply and demand, businesses that are just scraping by will no longer find it profitable to sell at the artificially low price, thus reducing the supply of the regulated product or service. The artificially low prices also increase the demand for the product, which creates a shortage. Price controls under emergency conditions, or “anti-price gouging laws,” are seen as an exception to this economic principle. What could be more immoral and exploitative than allowing greedy business men and women to profiteer off people suffering from a disaster? The economist Walter E. Williams disagrees with this moral stance, arguing that anti-price gouging laws do nothing to help disaster victims and are just as harmful as price controls under any other circumstances. Williams observes that since the tendency is for people to hoard scarce supplies during a disaster—leaving some people with too much of a product and others with none at all—allowing prices to rise freely during an emergency is beneficial for two reasons: first, customers are forced to economize on scarce resources, which leaves more available for everyone else, and second, the higher prices encourage businesses to divert more resources to the disaster area for profit. Williams concludes that “Anti-price gouging laws disrupt these two very important functions of the marketplace and enhance and prolong a disaster.”
Reference
Walter E. Williams (2020). “It’s not gouging; it’s the free market”. NWF Daily News. Retrieved from: https://www.nwfdailynews.com/story/opinion/columns/2020/04/05/walter-e-williams-its-not-gouging-its-free-market/1404506007/
Why Do Labor Unions Support Minimum Wage Laws?
Labor unions strongly advocate for minimum wage laws, which may seem unusual because few union workers earn minimum wage salaries. One could argue that labor unions advocate for higher minimum wages because they care for the rights of the entire working class, but Thomas Sowell has a more cynical view about their motives, arguing that labor unions support minimum wage laws instead to protect their own jobs from competition. Sowell notes that since many products can be made with a mixture of both low and high skilled labor, “experienced unionized workers are competing for employment against younger, inexperienced, and less skilled workers, whose pay is likely to be at or near the minimum wage. The higher the minimum wage goes, the more the unskilled and inexperienced workers are likely to be displaced by more experienced and higher skilled unionized workers” (p. 110). When program developers and evaluators examine the root causes of problems like youth unemployment, they should consider whether government policy is partly responsible for making young workers too expensive to hire.
Reference
Thomas Sowell (2011). The Thomas Sowell Reader. Basic Books.